Skip to content
Grist home
Support nonprofit news today

Articles by Sean Casten

Sean Casten is president & CEO of Recycled Energy Development, LLC, a company devoted to profitably reducing greenhouse emissions.

All Articles

  • Greenpeace and FOE call Climate Security Act too limited; too slow

    It's time to call the Lieberman-Warner love train back to the station. This is not to say that we don't urgently need to immediately start reducing atmospheric GHG concentrations and get policies in place that price carbon. It is instead simply the observation that as L-W morphs into ever greater complexity, it becomes an ever-worse way to meet that goal. Like Greenpeace and Friends of the Earth, I rather doubt that L-W will go anywhere close to far enough to cure AGW. But I am quite certain that the side effects of this purported cure are worse than the disease.

    Herewith, a few rather simple distinctions to prove the point. Consider each of the following either/or propositions, and ask yourself which would be a hallmark of good GHG policy.

    (Hint 1: the right answer is always A. Hint 2: the Lieberman-Warner answer is always B.)

  • The solution: Output-based standards

    This is the fifth and final post in a series on the details required to get carbon policy right. See also parts one, two, three, and four.

    So far, I've done a lot of complaining -- which, in and of itself, is just, well ... whiny. Here, then, is a solution.

    First, a very brief review:

    1. A test of good carbon policy is whether it encourages the private sector to invest capital in projects that will reduce GHG emissions.
    2. "Additionality" confuses carbon policy, by preferentially shifting investment toward less economic GHG-reduction technologies.
    3. Carbon taxes provide sticks without carrots, and thereby provide no direct incentive to those who might otherwise use carbon pricing to invest in projects that lower GHG emissions.
    4. Long-term carbon pricing is necessary to encourage private sector investment. Spots alone will not.
    5. Although not covered in this series, it bears repeating that auctions trump allocation.

    Unfortunately, virtually all of the GHG-reduction strategies currently in existence (e.g., Kyoto, RGGI) or being contemplated (e.g., Lieberman-Warner, California AB 32) fail one or more of the prior tests. Moreover, all those actual/proposed bills are really complicated, with many moving parts that are rife for gaming -- or, more charitably, significant legislative error. Here, then, is a better approach: output-based GHG regulation.

  • Joe Barton: Pork lover

    Joe Barton (R-Texas) spoke to the U.S. Energy Association yesterday and made it clear ($ub req'd) that he's going to do everything he can to block cap-and-trade legislation from coming out of Congress:

    As the Democrats move to pass climate change legislation this year, Rep. Joe Barton, R-Texas, will be there to fight them, he told the U.S. Energy Assn's annual membership meeting yesterday.

    As a senior member of the House Energy Committee, that's not a threat to be taken lightly. So why is he opposed?

    As justification, he cites both his passion for economic stewardship and his scientific judgment:

  • Spots vs. strips

    This is the fourth post in five-part series on the details required to get carbon policy right. See also parts one, two, and three.

    We now get into an issue that will seem a bit arcane, because no one's talking about it, at least not explicitly. But it's a real choice, and in many conversations about carbon policy we are implicitly getting it wrong.

    Should we price carbon in spots, or strips? Or, to take it out of financial jargon, should we:

    1. set up markets such that people who are selling or buying emissions credits have to go to the market with each incremental ton to determine what the price will be (a "spot" market), or
    2. set up markets such that buyers and sellers can enter into long-term contracts for the emissions they will produce/reduce (a "strip" market)?